1. Topic

  Raising Revenue by Ring-Fencing

2. Introduction

   

Ring-fencing is simply the principle by which revenue collected through actions in one area of activity can only be spent by authorities on related actions. Thus any fiscal revenue derived from taxation on transport, for example, should be kept in a separate pot to that from other revenue, and only be used to fund transport related activities.

The concept of ring-fencing is generally held to be a very sound one, as long as a reasonably broad view is taken over the breadth of the ring. Views also sometimes differ depending on the order in which the ‘carrot’ and ‘stick’ are applied. Are financial levies being put in place to finance other transport plans, or are the other plans merely a sweetener to make the levies more acceptable. Hopefully neither of these is the case and both play a role in the overall holistic integrated transport plan.

In general the principle encourages a strong view of economic sustainability with balances being made between revenue and spending within related areas of activity. There are, however, limits on how universally within local authority budgets ring-fencing should be employed as it could possibly restrict financing of areas of action which do not have a suitable, related, revenue stream. One other possible danger of this system is that public transport options may become dependent on revenue from car-drivers (or other non-sustainable transport methods).

3. Discussion

   

There are a number of justifications for ring-fencing to be employed. Firstly, in modern ‘free’ markets it is often claimed that taxpayers frequently object to paying taxes for the public good, but instead demand that they see some direct return for their money. In the UK this has been a frequently raised issue with regard to the comparatively high vehicle license tax and poor state of public highways. However, this argument is a very narrow view of how, ideally, ring-fencing should work. When viewed from the wider ‘polluter pays’ perspective, the car driver should not expect his road tax to be spent solely on improving conditions for him. The costs should be shared much more widely to compensate for the wider effects of his (and others) transport choice. These include contributing towards the costs of road accidents, helping cover the costs of people who suffer ill-health through pollution or stress related to noise, and building safe routes for pedestrians and cyclists away from roads. It can even be argued that car drivers should directly subsidise certain bus routes that are not financially viable due to under-use.

The highest profile use of ring fencing is where fiscal measures are used as a direct disincentive for people to drive (as in cases such as the congestion charge, the fuel-duty escalator, or parking place charges). In these cases it is necessary to provide a ‘carrot’ in addition to the ‘stick’ of financial penalties. For example, where access to a city centre is restricted using congestion/road-user charging, this is only justifiable if there are adequate good-quality public transport options available. Although a charge itself will bring about some possible improvement in bus operation due to less congested roads, if the revenue obtained from those people still opting to drive is used to further improve the public transport options than a much greater modal shift can be achieved.

4. Recommendation / Conclusion

   

· The concept of ring-fencing is generally held to be a very sound one, as long as a reasonably broad view is taken over the breadth of the ring. Views also sometimes differ depending on the order in which the ‘carrot’ and ‘stick’ are applied. Are financial levies being put in place to finance other transport plans, or are the other plans merely a sweetener to make the levies more acceptable. Hopefully neither of these is the case and both play a role in the overall holistic integrated transport plan.

· In general the principle encourages a strong view of economic sustainability with balances being made between revenue and spending within related areas of activity. There are, however, limits on how universally within local authority budgets ring-fencing should be employed as it could possibly restrict financing of areas of action which do not have a suitable, related, revenue stream. One other possible danger of this system is that public transport options may become dependent on revenue from car-drivers (or other non-sustainable transport methods).

5. Examples / Further Reading

   

Road-user Charging (UK)

Workplace Transport Levy (UK)

Congestion Charging (London, UK)

Further Examples:

Congestion charging in London and directing money to transport

6. Additional Documents / Web Links

   

Example of proposed congestion charge in Edinburgh: http://www.edinburgh.gov.uk/CETM/index.html?/NTI/FAQ.html

Last Updated


 

21st January 2005

Back